Phillips Curve R.I.P.
For a decade central banks have printed enormous
quantities of new money. The excuse is to stimulate the economy by reviving
inflation. However, the money has, for the most part, driven up the prices of
financial assets instead of consumer and producer prices. The result has been a
massive increase in the inequality of income, wealth, and opportunity.
The quantitative easing policy followed by central
banks is based on belief in an economic relationship between inflation and GDP
growth—the Phillips curve—that supply-side economics disproved during the
Reagan administration. The belief in the Phillips curve persists, because
supply-side economics was misrepresented by the financial media and neoliberal
junk economics.
The fact that something as straightforward and well
explained as supply-side economics can be misrepresented for 35 years should
give us all pause. When successive chairmen of the Federal Reserve and other
central banks have no correct idea what supply-side economics is, how can they
formulate a workable monetary policy? They cannot.
Phillips
Curve R.I.P.
Paul Craig Roberts
Republished with permission from The International
Economy
The Phillips Curve is the modern day version of the
Unicorn. People believe in it, but no one can find it. The Fed has been
searching for it for a decade and the Bank of Japan for two decades. So
has Wall Street.
Central banks’ excuse for their massive injections
of liquidity in the 21st century is that they are striving to stimulate the 2%
rate of inflation that they think is the requirement for sustained rises in
wages and GDP. In a total contradiction of the Phillips Curve, in Japan
massive doses of central bank liquidity have resulted in the collapse of both
consumer and financial asset prices. In the US the result has been a
large increase in stock averages propelled by unrealistic P/E ratios and
financial speculation resulting in Tesla’s capitalization at times exceeding
that of General Motors.
In effect pursuit of the Phillips Curve has become a
policy of ensuring financial stability of over-sized banks by continually
injecting massive amounts of liquidity. The result is greater financial instability.
The Fed is now confronted with a stock market disconnected from corporate
profits and consumer disposable income, and with insurance companies and
pension funds that have been unable for a decade to balance equity portfolios
with interest bearing debt instruments. Crisis is everywhere in the air.
What to do?
The Phillips Curve has been working its mischief for
a long time. During the Reagan administration the Philips Curve was responsible
for an erroneous budget forecast. In the 21st century the Phillips Curve is
responsible for an enormous increase in the money supply. The Reagan
administration paid a political price for placing faith in the Phillips
Curve. The price for the unwarranted creation of money by central banks
in the 21st century is yet to be paid.
The Phillips Curve once existed as a product of
Keynesian demand management and high tax rates on personal and investment
income. Policymakers pumped up consumer demand with easy money, but high
marginal tax rates impaired the responsiveness of supply. The consequence was
that prices rose relative to real output and employment. Supply-side economists
said the solution was to reverse the policy mix: a tighter monetary policy and
a “looser” fiscal policy in terms of lower marginal tax rates that would
increase the responsiveness of supply.
During the 1980s the economics establishment was too
busy ridiculing supply-side economics as “voodoo economics,” “trickle-down
economics,” “tax cuts for the rich,” and for allegedly claiming that tax cuts
pay for themselves, to notice what I pointed out at the time: the dreaded
Phillips Curve with its worsening trade-offs had disappeared. The high GDP
growth rates of the economic expansion beginning in 1983 were accompanied by
inflation that collapsed from near double-digit levels to 3.8% in 1983 and 1.1%
in 1986. Of course, the economics establishment wasn’t interested in such
embarrassing results, and so the story became the “Reagan deficits.” The
establishment reduced supply-side economics to the claim that tax cuts paid for
themselves, and the deficits proved supply-side economics to be wrong. Case
closed. This remains the story today as told by Wikipedia and in economic
classrooms.
The implementation of the Reagan administration’s
policy was disjointed, because Fed chairman Paul Volcker saw the supply-side
policy as a massive fiscal stimulation that would send already high inflation
rates soaring. Concerned that monetarists would blame him for what he
thought would be the inflationary consequences of irresponsible fiscal
stimulus, Volcker slammed on the monetary brakes two years before the tax rate
reductions were fully implemented. This was the main reason for the budget
deficits, not a “Laffer Curve” forecast that was not made. The Treasury’s
forecast was the traditional static revenue estimate that every dollar of tax
cut would cost a dollar of revenue.
In effect, the Phillips Curve became an ideology,
and economists couldn’t get free of it. Consequently, they have misunderstood
“Reaganomics” and its results and subsequently policymakers have inflicted
decades of erroneous policies on the world economy.
As so many have observed, if we don’t understand the
past, we cannot understand the present. To understand the past, let’s
begin with Reaganomics.
So what Was Reaganomics?
“Reaganomics” was the media’s name for supply-side
economics, which was a correction to Keynesian demand management. Worsening
“Phillips curve” tradeoffs between employment and inflation became a policy
issue during the Carter administration. The Keynesians had no solution except
an incomes policy that had no appeal to Congress. This opened the door to
a supply-side solution.
Demand management treats the aggregate supply
schedule as fixed. Fiscal and monetary policies were assumed to have no impact
on aggregate supply, a function of technology and resources. Changes in
marginal tax rates, for example, would, if expansionary (lower rates), move
aggregate demand along the aggregate supply schedule to higher employment; if
contractionary (higher rates), the policy would reduce inflation by reducing
aggregate demand and employment.
Supply-side economists said that some fiscal
policies directly shift the aggregate supply schedule and that neglect of this
by Keynesians was the explanation for the worsening Phillips curve trade-offs.
The Keynesian policy stimulated demand but high tax rates held back the
responsiveness of supply, so prices rose relative to output and employment.
This was the explanation of the worsening Phillips curve trade-offs.
Supply-side economists pointed out that marginal tax
rates affect two important relative prices. One is the price of leisure
in terms of forgone current income. The other is the price of current
consumption in terms of forgone future income. Thus, marginal tax
rates affect both the supply of labor and the supply of savings. The
higher the tax rate on labor income, the cheaper is leisure. The higher the tax
rate on investment income, the cheaper is current consumption or what is the
same thing, the higher is the opportunity cost of saving and investing.
Supply-side economists said that the solution to the
worsening Phillips curve trade-offs was to change the policy mix: tighten
monetary policy and “loosen” fiscal policy by lowering marginal tax rates.
Despite the clarity of my explanations in The
Supply-Side Revolution (Harvard University Press, 1984) The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance (1992), The
McGraw-Hill Encyclopedia of Economics (1994), Zeitschrift fur
Wirtschaftspolitik (38 Jahrgang 1989), Rivista di Politica
Economica (Maggio 1989), The Public Interest (Fall
1988) and http://www.paulcraigroberts.org/2017/07/17/supply-side-economics-theory-results/,
the myth has been established that supply-side economics is about tax cuts
paying for themselves. As the Wikipedia entry, for example, puts it, “The
Laffer curve is one of the main theoretical constructs of supply-side
economics.” This is nonsense. The issue that the policy addressed
was the worsening Phillips curve trade-offs, not raising revenues for the
government. As all official documents show, the Treasury’s revenue forecast of
the Reagan tax rate reduction is the Treasury’s static revenue forecast that
every dollar of tax reduction will lose a dollar of revenue.
Where then did the “Reagan deficits” come
from? The answer is that they came from the Phillips Curve. The Council
of Economic Advisers took the position that a forecast that departed
significantly from the Phillips curve belief that the economy could not grow
while inflation declined would lack credibility. A forecast of rapidly falling
inflation would especially discredit a budget that encompassed a tax rate
reduction that would be, despite our explanation, interpreted as a demand
stimulus policy. The budget director, David Stockman, and the White House
chief of staff took the position that the Republican Senate would not vote for
a tax rate reduction that enlarged the budget deficit. Therefore, against my
advice (I was Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy) the
inflation numbers in the six-year (1981-86) budget forecast were raised to
accommodate the Phillips curve and the Republican fear of budget deficits.
Having been present at Fed chairman Paul Volcker’s
meetings with the Fed’s outside consultants, I heard them tell Volcker that the
administration’s policy was a massive fiscal stimulus and that, in Alan
Greenspan’s words, “monetary policy is a weak sister; at best it can conduct a
weak rear-guard action.” I saw that Volcker was not going to follow the
Treasury’s request to gradually reduce the growth rate of money, but in order
to protect himself would throw on the brakes before any part of the phased-in
tax rate reduction had gone into effect.
And that is what Volcker did. Inflation
collapsed relative to forecast. The collapse in inflation collapsed GDP and the
tax base and is the origin of the budget deficits. The Reagan inflation
forecast was below the Carter administration and CBO forecasts, but high
relative to actual inflation. For example, Reagan’s budget forecast
inflation rates (1981-86) of 11.1%, 8.3%, 6.2%, 5.5%, 4.7%, and 4.2%.
Actual inflation was 8.9%, 3.8%, 3.8%, 3.9%, 3.8%, and 1.1%.
The budget deficits, which had been hidden by a
curtsy to the Phillips curve and Republican deficit phobia, became a weapon in
the Democrats’ hands. As a member of the Senate staff during 1977-78, I
succeeded in securing the support of leading Democrats, such as Russell Long,
chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, Lloyd Bentsen, chairman of the Joint
Economic Committee, and Sam Nunn on the Armed Services Committee, for a
supply-side policy. Indeed, the first Senate reports endorsing a
supply-side policy were issued by the Joint Economic Committee under Bentsen’s
chairmanship in 1979 and 1980. Support for a supply-side policy had also
spread into the House Democrats. House Speaker Tip O’Neil introduced a
Democratic supply-side alternative to Reagan’s. The only way Reagan could
differentiate his tax cut from the Democratic alternative was by indexing the
tax rates for inflation (beginning in the mid-1980s).
Despite the willingness of Democrats to support a
supply-side policy, the White House staff wanted to give Reagan a “political
victory” by picking a fight and cutting the Democrats out of the tax
bill. This “victory” turned to ashes when the Phillips curve proved to be
bogus. Democrats, media, and academics turned on the administration,
accusing it of a Laffer curve forecast, and Wall Street economists kept
interest rates high with their absurd prediction that budget deficits resulting
from the collapse of inflation would cause inflation to explode.
In the United States the Phillips curve has
disappeared. Not even a decade of quantitative easing and an enormous
expansion in the Fed’s balance sheet have been able to bring it back. The
Fed is still trying and remains unsure whether it can raise the short term
interest rate by 25 basis points. And this despite enormous budget
deficits. The miniscule rate increases about which the Fed worries are not
even real increases as they do not offset the low reported inflation.
Those who recognize the Phillip Curve’s demise
attribute it to globalization, that is, to the offshoring of high-productivity,
high value-added manufacturing jobs that have destroyed manufacturing unions.
However, the Phillips Curve disappeared long before globalization took off. The
US 70% tax rate on investment income and the 50% tax rate on personal income
from the Phillips Curve era have been absent for 35 years. To resurrect the
Phillips Curve, the responsiveness of output to demand would have to again be
impaired.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.